Use Sophia to knock out your gen-ed requirements quickly and affordably. Learn more
×

Utility Theory

Author: Sophia
what's covered
This tutorial will cover utility theory, focusing on what a utility function measures, interpreting preference maps, and how to determine a consumer's preference using indifference curves and the law of diminishing returns.

Our discussion breaks down as follows:

  1. Utility Function
  2. Indifference Curves and Utility
  3. Consumer Preferences: Indifference Curves
  4. Shape of Indifference Curves and the Law of Diminishing Marginal Return
  5. Marginal Rate of Substitution


1. Utility Function

We as consumers have to make choices every day. We are also very aware of our constraints, which are primarily time and income.

Therefore, how do we make choices that maximize our utility?

hint
Remember that the term "utility" equates satisfaction; it's what we get out of something. Therefore, we clearly want to maximize it.

Now, the general form of a utility function is like any function. Utility is a function of variables x, y, and z, which simply means that our utility--or the satisfaction that we get out of something--is dependent on these various factors.

formula to know
Utility Function

U equals F left parenthesis X comma space Y comma space Z right parenthesis

Utility is going to be different for everyone, because we are not all the same. We don't all enjoy the same thing, so therefore we won't get the same amount of satisfaction out of everything.

The utility function defined, then, is a formula used to represent consumer preferences. The utility function itself will result in an indifference curve mapping where each curve corresponds to a higher level of utility.

term to know
Utility Function
A formula used to represent consumer preferences; the utility function will result in an indifference curve mapping where each curve corresponds to a higher level of utility.


2. Consumer Choices and Utility

Let's begin our discussion of consumer choices by looking at a simplified model of a two-good economy.

IN CONTEXT

In this two-good economy, you must choose between chicken and beef for dinner each night of the week. These are your only two choices.

How much of each will you consume each week? Is it the same for everyone? Obviously not.

Different consumers will have different preferences, and individual preferences affect how much chicken versus beef a person chooses.

We are going to look at utility on a preference map, which will include every possible combination of chicken and beef.

Each combination will give us some amount of satisfaction or utility, measured by a number.

Note, however, that the numbers are different for everybody and the scale itself does not matter. For instance, it doesn't matter if the numbers are 1 through 10, or 100 to 500.

The idea is that we are looking at each combination that provides some amount of utility, and it is increasing as we draw more and more indifference curves mapped out away from the origin, which we will illustrate shortly.

Individual preferences will affect, obviously, how much chicken versus beef an individual chooses. It will also affect a person's choice if their income or the price of chicken or beef changes.

big idea
Each consumer has their own utility functions which show their preference behavior; they are unique to an individual.


3. Consumer Preferences: Indifference Curves

You may recall that when discussing consumers' preference behavior, we make three assumptions:

Assumption Definition
Completeness There must be a number or rank for every combination of chicken and beef, indicating either preference or indifference.
Transitivity There must be consistency and rationality in our preferences (e.g., I like chicken more than beef, and I like beef more than shrimp; therefore, I must like chicken more than shrimp.
Non-Satiation Our utility increases as we consume more; in other words, more is better. We can always throw any excess out if we do not actually want to consumer it.

Indifference curves are defined as a graphical depiction of the utility function. Utility increases as these mapped indifference curves move away from the origin.

Here is an indifference curve that maps the two goods in our two-good economy--beef on the x-axis and chicken on the y-axis.

It shows all possible combinations of chicken and beef. All of the points (A, B, and C) represent combinations or bundles that the consumer is indifferent to--which is why we call it an indifference curve--because they yield the same utility; therefore, the consumer does not prefer one over the other.

File:9366-Screen_Shot_2019-05-02_at_9.00.58_PM.png

For instance, this consumer would enjoy the same amount of utility out of point A, which is consuming eight chicken and one beef, as he or she would out of point B, which is consuming four chicken and three beef, or point C, consuming two chicken and seven beef.

Now, if this consumer can get more and more of the two goods, then each of these indifference curves represent combinations that yield more of both, if that becomes possible.

As we have indifference curves moving away from the origin, the utility is increasing.

File:9367-Screen_Shot_2019-05-05_at_3.33.01_PM.png

This consumer would have higher utility on Indifference Curve 2 than Curve 1, for instance, because he or she gets more chicken and beef. The highest utility would be on Curve 3.

big idea
There is an indifference curve for every level of utility.

term to know
Indifference Curves
Graphical depiction of the utility function; utility increases as the mapped indifference curves move away from the origin


4. Shape of Indifference Curves and the Law of Diminishing Marginal Return

So, why do indifference curves have this particular shape?

This is an important concept, so let's explore this further. Look at the indifference curve below, with its four points--A, B, C, and D.

Each of these point represents a different combination, or bundle, of chicken and beef.

File:9368-Screen_Shot_2019-05-05_at_3.41.18_PM.png

Notice that each time this consumer moves from one point to the next, she is gaining two more beef.

So, starting at A where she has almost no beef and all chicken:

  • From A to B: She is willing to give up five chicken to gain two beef.
  • From B to C: She is willing to give up two chicken to gain two beef.
  • From C to D: She is willing to give up less than one chicken to gain two beef.

Why is she giving up less and less chicken each time to get the same amount of beef?

It is because of the law of diminishing marginal return which states that at some point, in either production or consumption, the economic agent will experience a decrease in the level of production or utility associated with an increase in the production or consumption of an additional unit.

hint
The key word in this definition is "additional unit" because marginal is defined as "additional."

Looking back at our example, at point A, the consumer has almost no beef at all. Therefore, going from point A to B, she is willing to give up quite a bit of chicken to have a variety.

At point B, now she has some beef. She is willing to give up some chicken, but not as much as before.

Finally, at point C, she has more beef and little chicken. She is not willing to give up the little chicken she has for even more beef.

big idea
The more we have of something, we gain less additional utility from consuming more of it. At some point, our additional, or marginal, utility diminishes.

Note, however, that this does not mean we still do not enjoy it. It simply means we are willing to give up less in order to get more of it because the additional satisfaction gained from it is tapering.

So basically, here's what I want you to think about when you hear about diminishing marginal utility, or diminishing marginal return. The more we have of something, we are gaining less additional utility from consuming more of it. At some point our additional or marginal utility diminishes.

EXAMPLE

For example, when you are eating a Thanksgiving meal, you likely enjoy most of that meal, but don't you tend to enjoy the first few bites the most? After you've had that first helping, you may go back for a second helping, so you are still enjoying it and your total utility is still increasing, but your additional, or marginal utility, is starting to taper or diminish.

term to know
Law of Diminishing Marginal Return
At some point, in either production or consumption, the economic agent will experience a decrease in the level of production or utility associated with an increase in the production or consumption of an additional unit


5. Marginal Rate of Substitution

This brings us to the marginal rate of substitution, which is actually just the slope of the indifference curve, which shows how much we are willing to give up of one good to gain more of the other.

File:9369-Screen_Shot_2019-05-05_at_3.41.18_PM.png

Notice that where the slope is quite steep, we are willing to give up a significant amount to gain a small amount on the x-axis. Then the slope becomes less steep and begins to flatten as we move along the curve.

This is why indifference curves are shaped this way and are convex to the origin, due to the law of diminishing marginal return.


summary
Today we learned that a utility function measures a consumer's preferences, which are different for everyone. We learned that when we map out this utility, it is called a preference map, which is made up of indifference curves. These indifference curves get their shape because of the law of diminishing marginal return. Lastly, we learned that the slope of the indifference curve is defined as the marginal rate of substitution.

Source: Adapted from Sophia instructor Kate Eskra.

Terms to Know
Indifference Curves

Graphical depiction of the utility function; utility increases as the mapped indifference curves move away from the origin.

Law of Diminishing Marginal Return

At some point, in either production or consumption, the economic agent will experience a decrease in the level of production or utility associated with an increase in the production or consumption of an additional unit.

Utility Function

A formula used to represent consumer preferences; the utility function will result in an indifference curve mapping where each curve corresponds to a higher level of utility.